Why a sliding scale matters (health care costs)

So.  Months ago I started this health-care cost topic.  We started off on the topic of routine costs.

And to summarize the main point of that post: Routine health care — all those preventative check-ups, and the care and treatment of run-of-the-mill colds and flu and stubbed toes is not something we actually “insure”.   These are planned expenses.

Insurance is the means of having everyone contribute a modest amount to a funding pool, so that the few who suffer the unlikely catastrophe are not devasted by the enormous costs.    So, we insure against a car wreck — many drivers will never be in one.  But gasoline and oil changes are part of our routine costs — costs every driver will incur, no matter how careful you are.

When we say we have “insurance” to cover routine health care costs, what we really have is a pre-payment plan.

(The same can be said of larger unplanned-but-still-expected expenses.  Sprained ankle, the weird stomach thing that felt like a heart-attack but you went to the ER and it turned out you were okay, the  routine delivery of a healthy baby.   You might not know exactly when and what expenses are coming your way, but come on, you knew something was bound to happen.  You set aside an “emergency fund” of cash to cover these odds and ends.)

***

On the other end of the health care spectrum are insurable costs.  Not everyone will get cancer, or suffer massive injuries in a car wreck, or contract some other equally expensive ailment.   Insurance to cover the cost of treatment makes sense.   We all contribute a modest amount towards paying those expenses, and if you are the unlucky one, the pool of funding is there to help pay your enormous bills.

–> Now it should be observed that as with home insurance or car insurance, there are factors that affect how likely you are to suffer the big disaster.   Within reason, it makes sense to allow the health-care corrollary to safe-driver and good-homeowner discounts.  Recognizing, however, that unlike obeying the speed limit or installing a sprinker system, a significant chunk of a person’s health is not within their control.  Like being male & under 25, slightly elevated rates are understandable, but it isn’t fair to price a guy completely off the streets for something he can’t control.

But here’s where health insurance differs entirely from car and home insurance: You can’t buy a cheaper body.

If my budget is tight, I can choose to live in a small home and drive an inexpensive, easily-repaired, fuel-efficient used car.    My insurance rates will, correspondingly, be lower.  Likewise, my routine maintenance costs will be lower.

(Indeed, how do we measure a living wage?  We aren’t looking for a wage that will pay for a mansion and a cadillac.  We look at whether it will cover such basic needs as modest housing and frugal transportation.)

With health care, we aren’t so lucky.  If I take a big pay cut, I can’t go sell my McMansion body and rent a modest little apartment of a body instead.  I can’t take my late-model BMW body to Car Max, and come home with a cute little ’92 Civic in exhange.   I can’t even park my gas-guzzler body in the driveway and take public transit for all my bodily needs instead.  Indeed, for the most part I never got to choose whether I wanted an expensive body or frugal one to begin with.  I’m stuck with whatever body I was given, and bodies aren’t given out according to income.

What does this mean for health insurance?

It means that the point where health care becomes unaffordable depends on your income.   Partly a living-wage problem, of course.   But let’s imagine a worker earning enough to cover routine appointments and modest amount of emergency health-care besides.  The illness that is an inconvenience and a bit of a strain to a wealthier family is something that would be absolutely unaffordable to a person of more modest means.

(Check out the wheelchair world for a specific example: Some people can just go out and buy the chair that suits them best, even though it costs something in between a high-end racing bike and a quality new car, depending on their needs.  Other people have to hope someone, anyone, is willing to fund a chair approximating what they need to function in a healthy manner.)

It also means that the ability to afford insurance premiums varies.  How much of your monthly budget can you set aside?

***

Two very obvious points, I know.  And hence the importance of sliding-scale charges for health care.  If we mean to have a fair health care system, it is reasonable to give discounts to people who cannot afford as much.   Kind of the way we have student discounts for opera tickets.

Does that mean we have to go with a tax-funded, nationalized health-care system?  Not necessarily.  Physicians could be allowed to post discounted prices.    Insurance companies could be allowed to issue policies where the premiums and deductibles are percentages-of-income rather than flat rates.   Employers that offer health insurance benefits could be allowed to vary the “employee’s share” of the expense according the employee’s income.   If we are creative enough to think up double-coupons, Sam’s Club, and Early Bird Specials, we can figure this out, too.

On the other hand . . .

Something the WSJ hasn’t taken up yet, and really, really needs to be addressed in this whole health-care-reform debate:  The way our current insurance system supresses entrepreneurship.

What works well right now is the company-sponsored health insurance plan.   Go to work for a large organization with good benefits, and you’re in pretty good shape, healthcare-wise.  Thus it goes against the grain, when thinking about improving access to health care, to do anything to fiddle with the one part of our system that is actually providing decent care.

–> But because it is the *only* method that is working well, people who need good insurance at an affordable rate are essentially barred from entrepreneurship.

It needn’t be this way.  There is nothing special about insurance pools formed by grouping co-workers.  Individuals could be be grouped by location, by industry, by favorite color — however you like, the principle of pooling risk works the same, as long as you have a large number of buyers over whom to spread the risk.

–>  A reform of the insurance industry could open up affordable insurance options to individual buyers, regardless of their employer.  Transparent pricing policies would further enable individuals to make confident health care purchases without relying on an insurance company to do all the negotiating for reasonable rates.

But as the system stands now, large companies are able to suck in a disproportionate amount of talent because they hold the key to reliable, affordable health care.  And specifically, they are able to suck in over-qualified talent because of the cost/price differential between health care costs in the corporate versus the individual markets.

***

People work around it.  You start your own business on the evenings and weekends, and hold onto the corporate job until you finally have enough income to go on your own.  Or your spouse works the corporate job, any job, just to get the benefits, so you can be covered while you get the business up and running.   As you grow your little company, at first you try to hire employees who already have insurance through a parent or spouse or a 2nd job.  There are ways to work the system.

But I think economically it is a drain.  We would be better off– and better able to whether economic downturns — if our structures for providing health care were more favorable towards entrepreneurship and small businesses.

health-care: private versus public rationing

One of the arguments in favor of Obama’s health care program is something like this:

“Insurance companies effectively ration care, too — deciding what treatments the insurance will and will not cover.  Therefore, going to a government-run program will make no difference.  Those who complain about possible ‘rationing’ are throwing out a red herring.”

I disagree, for all the reasons Darwin Catholic lists here.

***

[Review: I am not a person who is opposed to health care reform.  Indeed, I am a person who has written on this very blog about what kinds of health care reform I think are needed.  I have specifically given examples of why charitable assistance is needed for those who can’t afford adequate health care.  I just happen to think that going to a single-payer, government-run system might not be the best of our available options.]

***

I would add that in my opinion, effective health care reform would free up our insurance system so that consumers have *more choice* and *more information* in order to choose an insurance progam that best meets their preferences.  For example, someone has proposed making insurance portable from job to job.

–> I think the idea is that insurance pools would not be formed by companies on behalf of their employees, but rather by individuals.  The role of the employer would be to provide the means to pay for the insurance.

***

And of course for all this to work, yeah, you’d need pricing transparency.  You’ve got to know what your costs are, if you mean to control them.  You just have to.

Good ideas on health care reform

Glad to see the Journal has finally started running op-eds with proposals for solutions to the health care situation, rather than just storming against the Obamacare thing.

What I’ve seen that I really like:  Reforming and expanding Healthcare Savings Accounts, combined with high-deductible insurance policies.  And then providing health care stamps, analagous to food stamps, with which people who have legitimate financial need can fill their HSA.

This seems to me like a relatively efficient, manageable solution that offers a real possibility of helping the poor without undermining the many things that actually work in American healthcare.

I also, of course, am firmly convinced that we need pricing transparency.  Just no way you can run an efficient market when nobody even knows the product prices.

***

One thing I’d like to argue about:  Saw a comment a week or so ago about how Americans, compared to other nations, spend the most on healthcare, but do not have the best health outcomes.  To which I’d observe:  If you are in poor health, you will spend more money on healthcare.

I believe our obesity rates alone probably explain a significant portion of the gap.  We as a nation choose to be in poorer health than we must, and then we choose to treat the health problems we give ourselves (understandably!).  No surprise the figures run as they do.

[There is also a significant amount of money spent on elective procedures such as cosmetic surgery that are may be bundled into our ‘healthcare expenses’, but have nothing to do with making people healthier.]

None of which is to deny that our health care situation has its problems.  Just that the raw statistics do not tell you what the problem really is.

May the Best Budgeter Win

A few months ago (yeah, I know), I picked up a copy of The Medieval Military Revolution (Barnes & Noble 1998 – originally written in 1995 — Edited by Andrew Ayton & J.L. Price).  Been sitting on my shelf, inherited from TR, yet unread.  I was looking for something I didn’t find there, but I came across this thought in the editor’s introduction:

Those that live by the sword shall die by the sword, and this can be applied in a sense to governments and even states as well.  States went bankrupt, at least technically, through the cost of war, and the fiscal strain of long-term involvement in warfare was perhaps the single most important threat to political stability even in this most turbulent of periods.

In this case, the editor is writing about the mid-16th to mid-17th century.  But every century has its nations, and the realities of economics and defense don’t disappear over time.

When I was in high school economics, I can remember people trying to argue that somehow the US’s national debt just didn’t matter.  We were too big to fail, or by some bit of magic we could borrow as much as we wanted and nothing would really happen . . . it was bizarre. Didn’t make sense then, and still doesn’t.  I suppose we could always stiff our creditors in the end, but even that has its consequences.

The US is a mighty wealthy nation.  Wealthy people can waste a lot of resources and not feel the consequences the way poorer neighbors would.  But there are limits to our wealth.  We can’t just magically spend on anything we decide we want — even we must pick and choose.

***

And anytime we borrow? We have to pay it back out of future wealth.  The only time borrowing fuels growth is when the money borrowed is invested in something that makes us more productive. The hallmark of a chronic debtor, of course, is the conviction that every debt really was necessary, really did make the debtor ‘better off’.

But reality isn’t so.

In the current economic quagmire, households, businesses, and governments that had previously acted prudently and with fiscal restraint are managing fairly well.  A neighbor was laid off, but fortunately he had savings, was living beneath his means — he has a little cushion to get by while he looks for a new job.  The greatest crises today are coming among those who were massively in debt a year ago or more, and don’t know how to get by without yet more debt.  (Or, of course, stiffing their creditors.)

–>  Not talking here about those families and businesses that did everything ‘right’ during the flush times (which were not, for them, all that flush), but still struggle today.  Not talking about those whose reverses have been far greater than anyone could plan against.  Prudence today won’t withstand every possible storm tomorrow. But it sure improves your odds.

***

So I’m a bit alarmed by the current rush to spend, spend, spend.  Oh and it isn’t a democrat’s problem — I had a pit in my stomach prior to the presidential election, knowing that I could count on either party to be just as irresponsible.  I’m alarmed by things like trying to create new government-sponsored insurance programs *for people who already have health insurance*, when we haven’t sucessfully put together a program for those who don’t.

–> Frankly I’m really dissappointed in the democrats, because they aren’t actually coming through on helping people who actually need help.  Tons and tons of spending on vague programs to ‘stimulate’.  Er, how about we just get everyone who needs food fed?  Houses for *actual homeless people*?

A more personal example: I’ve a friend who has an undiagnosed breathing problem. She *stops breathing*.  She can’t afford a doctor’s visit to diagnose the problem.  Mmn . . . how ’bout we stimulate the economy by making it possible to get in for a doctor’s appointment if you’re a person who can’t work because you can’t, uh, breathe reliably??  That cash would trickle into the pockets of a receptionist, a maintenance guy, a lab worker, an MD — *and* we’d have a person who might be able to breathe all the time? And thus be able to go get a job? Hmmn?

***

End of the rant.  Have a good week.  Soon as I find my lost book, I’ll have a review up on the other blog.  Meanwhile am trying, as always, to clean the house, educate the children, exercise the ol’ mind, body & spirit, and all that other vocation-y stuff.  Hope y’all are doing well.  Oh, and hey, to keep you busy during my slackerlyness, here’s another cornucopia of social-issues rants: http://www.frontporchrepublic.com/ . Thanks to Bethune Catholic for the link.

routine care and the uninsured

Anna in the combox on my last post points out that I glossed over the importance of routine care as a cost-savings measure.   She shares a specific example of a family member’s costly (and potentially deadly) health problem that could have been caught and treated earlier via routine care.   WSJ this morning has an article about the large number of clients health insurers are losing to layoffs.

–> Given the cost of privately-obtained insurance, and given that an unemployed person will naturally put off lower-priority expenses, the layoffs *will* mean people skip on routine care that could have saved much time and distress.

***

What’s the solution?  I don’t know.  It’s really tempting to, say, add some kind of health care aid as part of unemployment compensation. It seems pretty simple – in addition to that paltry sum of unemployment payments, you get a packet of health-care stamps or some such thing.

Objections?

Doing so creates an incentive to not return to employment unless it provides a better package than the unemployment package.  The way our unemployment system works now, we assume that you were pretty pulled together before you were laid off — you kept yourself healthy, you are up-to-date on your physical, you have some emergency savings, you weren’t living above your means.  Unemployment payments are, in my state anyway, a little something extra to tide you over while you scramble for a new job, any job.

Most Americans, it turns out, aren’t actually living this way.  Americans are, on average, in poor health, they haven’t got savings, they are in the habit of using credit all the time.   Not poor Americans, *all* Americans.   Conservatives have a well-trained stinginess-reflex that recoils at the thought of aiding and abetting these bad habits.   Liberals, on the other hand, might recognize the need for change, but observe that you won’t have much chance for self-improvement if you’ve just dropped dead.

My intuition is that the solution lies in the middle.  It is reasonable to set up some mechanism for providing routine preventative care and emergency health care to people whose situation falls outside the norm.  Whether due to temporary unemployment or some tragic longterm problem.  We should think about how to do so efficiently. (Health care stamps? Clinics? Private Charities? Insurance vouchers? School nurses? So many possibilities.)

And then, separately, we need to be working on addressing the myriad problems that are making our health care crisis so much more onerous than it ought to be.

Taking Apart Health Costs, part II

The other week I made some opening remarks.  The next thing I want to do is look at the different kinds of health care costs.  I think costs can be divided into three different categories:

-Well Visits / Routine Care

-Minor mishaps

-Major events

Cost-wise,  each of three works differently.  From an insurance point of view, the funding of each category of costs ought to work differently.  Today I’ll look at the first type of health care cost, routine care.  Then I’ll take on the other two categories in turn, in subsequent posts.

***

“Well Visits” or Routine Care

This kind of health care is what you do to keep yourself healthy.  The periodic physical or well-child visit, vaccines as appropriate, routine screenings like getting your cholesterol checks, or having the dermatologist look for suspicious moles.

As with all health care, exactly who needs what and when is debatable.   One real challenge for managing a nation’s health care needs is deciding what those needs are. If you happen to agree with the manager of your health care plan, you are going to be fairly happy.  If you find that your health care plan covers — even insists — on care you don’t want, and will not cover the care you do want, you won’t be so happy.

–> Fondness for nationalized health care plans, or for company-sponsored plans, often divides based on that question.  Any just health care system will find the right balance between protecting a legitimate amount of disagreement, while neither blindly funding true quack treatments, nor refusing care that could reasonably be needed.  No easy task.  I am leery of anyone who claims this is easily determined, and that the rest of us should just go along.

A second point to remember is that our current models for administering routine care — and thus the costs associated with that care — are not set in stone.  Some of the tasks of well-care could be done by the individual — such as tracking your own family’s weight and height.   Where a health care professional is required, models for economic delivery of routine care should not be dismissed.  There is much to be said for the corner pharmacy running flu-shot clinics, or the local hospital dispatching a team of cholesterol-checkers for a one-day-blitz at the company cafeteria.

–> When we look at health care reform, we should be willing to think outside the box about ways to reduce costs, but also allow that some patients really do need a level of closer monitoring and hand-holding.

The good news is that patients won’t generally double-dip if there are multiple venues for the same kind of care — no one gets a flu shot at Walgreens *and* from the doctor’s office, just because both are available.  What we sometimes think of as ‘scattershot’, really is not.  A patient will reliably avoid excess poking and prodding, and given multiple choices for receiving routine care, will usually pick the one most suited to his situation.

On the topic of routine care, we should go ahead and acknowledge that some elements of well-care are most important as compensation for poor behavior.  A good health care system will combat these problems at the source.  In other words, a good health care system might involve making it possible for kids to walk to school and play outside more.

–> No no! I am *not* suggesting the Department of Transportation become an office of a National Health Bureau!  What I am suggesting is that ‘health care reform’ is much more than creating a national insurance program.  By their nature, the nations’ health concerns need to be attacked from multiple angles.  One element of managing routine health care costs is to be looking for ways to reduce the need for preventative care.

Try not to squirm as I observe: we should not overlook our nation’s moral climate when trying to find ways to reduce health care costs.   I don’t say leave people hanging out to dry because of their past mistakes; but by all means, do help avert disaster and instruct on avoiding more problems in the future.  A legitimate part of routine care is education and assistance in adopting healthy behaviors.

***

After all this attacking of health care costs from without and within, we are still left us with some routine well-care that is useful and well worth our while.  Having acknowledged that your list of the right and good may be different from mine, assume for the rest of this article that when I talk about ‘routine care’ I am referring to those well-care practices that you happen to think are money well spent.  Here are some observations specifically about the nature of these types of costs:

The payoff is not immediate. Break your leg, and you have no doubt that the services of a good bonesetter are well worth your while.  Spending $120 for your physician to tell you your toddler looks normal?  Might make you feel good, but when money is tight, you are going to be tempted to just look around at the local playgroup and be content your kid looks okay and seems normal enough.  If you haven’t dropped dead yet, what’s another month or two before going in for that physical . . .

. . . And frankly, most people who go in for routine care didn’t end up “needing it”.   For every baby saved from disaster by a routine a well-visit, there are plenty that could have skipped the appointment and been the none the worse.  At the height of the polio epidemics, most people managed just fine without the vaccine.  Trouble is, if you’re the one who did need the care, you would have been sunk without it.

–> So when we look at the benefits of routine care, we have to acknowledge that we are checking all in the hope of saving some.  Well worth it.  As a result, we have to overcome our natural stinginess — towards ourselves and towards others.

***

Currently, there are three ways to pay for well-care in the United States.  One is to have the care paid for by an employer-sponsored health care plan.  The second is to qualify for a government-run program.  The third is to pay for it yourself (or persuade a loving friend or relative to pay it for you).  Each of these is valid.

Employers have a legitimate interest in ensuring employees and their dependents receive routine care.  The expense up front can pay for itself by saved sick days and avoiding more expensive treatments down the road.  It is not unreasonable to continue to allow employers to subsidize health care costs.

The government likewise benefits from a healthy populace, for the same reason.  Healthy citizens are productive citizens who can contribute to wider society.  Two obvious cautions:

1) The US government does not have a perfect track record in its management of other efforts.  We would be unwise to assume it will be able to manage a national health care system any better than it can manage any other department.

2) As with employers, the utilitarian interest is limited.  The government benefits greatly from cultivating intelligent, hard-working, highly-capable individuals.  There is a temptation to limit care only to those who show promise, and discretely push aside those who don’t offer sufficient promise for future contributions.   The current rate of abortion for children diagnosed with Down Syndrome is telling.  There is already a strong tendency in our country to consider life itself as really only appropriate for those who offer the rest of us more perceived “benefit” than cost.  There is no reason to think that government-run health care will be anything other than a reflection of wider society’s values.

Individuals and their immediate relations are the obvious primary beneficiaries of routine care.  Well it is reasonable for the government or employers to fund routine care when individuals might otherwise neglect it, the cost of routine care properly belongs to the individual. The most effective health care system, in my opinion, will help individuals make wise decisions on which routine care is needed, and provide a convenient means of setting aside funding for that care.

***

What about Insurance?

Health “insurance” for routine care is a misnomer.  There is no ‘insurance’ to it.  Insurance is the pooling of risk.  I pay homeowner’s insurance so that in the unlikely event that my house catches fire, I can benefit from the my neighbors’ contributions to the insurance program,  and thus receive money to rebuild my home.  With true insurance, all participants contribute a share of the cost of one person’s disaster.  If I’m lucky, I’ve ‘thrown my money away’ — I’ll never collect.  If I’m unlucky, I can be rescued from an emergency I never could have saved for on my own.

Routine care, in contrast, is an expected cost.   It’s not a question of ‘whether I will want a tetanus shot’.  I want one.  Someone has to pay for it.  Likewise there is no magical cost savings by having 100% of newborn babies get their well-visits paid for by the insurance company.  In a perfectly run nationalized health care system, the cost of routine care is exactly the same as if each of us just paid out of our own pocket.

In the case of routine care, all that an insurance program does is act as a middle man.  Now there can be benefits to middle men.  My insurance program (Blue Cross Blue Shield) regularly pays a lower rate than the retail price on my medical bills.  Even when my insurance “doesn’t cover” a particular service, I only have to pay the ‘negotiated rate’, effectively cutting my cost in half over the list price.  Kind of a Sam’s Club for health care.

–> To the extent that an insurance program is providing an effective tool for matching health care consumers and providers, it is a worthy organization.  Just like your local grocery stores is ‘merely a middleman’ that makes it a lot easier and more efficient to feed your family.  But insurance is no more the means of getting health care than the grocery store produces food.

Now one advantage of an insurance program is that it forces you to set aside the cash.  If you are a poor saver, purchasing an insurance policy that bundles routine care with your other health care needs is a way of tricking yourself into saving for routine care. Indeed, the company selling you an insurance policy for non-routine care has an interest in motivating you through low co-pays to get to the doctor early and often, in the hopes of warding off a more expensive condition down the road.  Kind of like your home insurance company benefits if you install a sprinkler system (to put out house fires), and replace that old wiring before it catches fire.

–> But all the same, the routine care you need is not an insurable risk, it is a regularly scheduled expense.  For this reason, if ordinary workers cannot afford to pay routine medical costs out of pocket, the problem lies elsewhere than a lack of insurance.  Maybe costs are too high.  Maybe the workers aren’t earning a living wage.  Maybe workers are lousy at managing their money.  Insurance programs may or may not turn out to be the easiest way to compensate for the underlying problem.  But lack of “insurance” coverage for routine care is not, in itself, the problem, and more than lack of food insurance is the reason people are malnourished, or lack of clothing insurance is the reason I dress so shoddily.

Keep in mind: There will always be people who cannot pay their ordinary expenses.  People who cannot, for whatever reason, pay their own food and housing bills, likewise will need assistance paying for even routine preventative medical care.  “The poor will always be with us” and all that.   We should distinguish these ought-to-be-exceptional cases from the needs of ordinary citizens.   There is a place for soup kitchens and food stamps; there is a place for charitable health clinics and health-care stamps.  But we shouldn’t therefore assume that the whole country needs to sign up for charitable relief.

***

All that rambling to summarize just a few points:

Routine Care costs can be reduced, but not eliminated. We will get a lot of bang for our health care efforts by working to find ways to reduce our need for routine care, and to delivery efficiently what care is needed.

Routine Care costs go to 100% of citizens. By its definition.  There is no risk to be pooled. What we think of as “insurance coverage” for routine care is actually just a means of either forcing ourselves to pay for the care, or getting someone else to pay for it instead.

There are multiple beneficiaries to routine care. The primary beneficiary is the individual receiving the care, and a just health care system makes makes it simple and convenient for the individual to access affordable routine care.  But there are times in places when others benefit, and it is reasonable to allow those others to pay for that care.

***

So what do I think about “Insurance” Programs for routine care? I think they have their place, as part of a multi-faceted approach to providing health care.  But we should recognize them for what they are — savings plans, middle men, and cost-shifters.  We should consider whether other changes that facilitate individual health-care savings would be more effective.

And what do I think is the number one thing-we-haven’t-tried-yet that is worth exploring? Price lists.  Publicly posted.  Not just the ‘list price’ but the agreed-on prices for different classes of consumers.  I think we kid ourselves about ‘managing health care costs’ when virtually nobody even knows what those costs really are.

Taking Apart Health Care Costs, intro

Busy day on the WSJ’s editorial page.  Top center is a nice letter-to-the-editor proposing a realistic compromise concerning mark-to-market and regulatory capital.  See, I knew I wasn’t crazy.

Jim Curley will be thrilled to see someone else advocating for smaller businesses, down in the lower right hand section of the letters.  Not sure how one would make it happen, but there is a valid point: if a business is “too big to fail”, it is too big.   You can’t have your whole economy living and dying on the wisdom of a single CEO or board of directors.  An alternate view: maybe no company is too big to fail.  You can let it be big, as long as you are willing to let it fail.  Something to think about it; I don’t have a fully-formed opinion yet.

And then the topic I do want to cover today is introduced in “National Health Preview”, a critique of Massachusetts’ health reform results.  Not supportive to say the least.

***

Health care reform and universal health care coverage is a thorny issue, and I wanted to break apart the cost structure, and maybe add a few other comments, to help us think about it.

The first thing to keep in mind, and forgive me for stating the obvious, is that someone has to pay for it. I say so because health care is expensive, and if you won’t or can’t pay your own bill, it comes out of your neighbor’s pocket.  If you are a person who has good health care coverage, can pay your own bills, and lives comfortably, take a look at your budget.  What several thousands of dollars a year in other spending are you willing to give up so that your less-fortunate fellow citizens can enjoy the same health care benefits you do?  A less expensive car?  A smaller house?  You have to be willing to sacrifice, if you really mean to provide everyone in America with the health care that we tend to consider our due.

And that leads to a problem: Everyone dies. And bunches of us won’t do it on the cheap.  A lot of us are going to die after a long illness that can be treated for a time, to prolong our life and make it more comfortable.   What is an an extra year of life worth?  It is priceless.  How much is it worth to ensure that you or a loved one does not suffer needlessly in the final days, months, or years of your life?

–> When it comes down to it, our wants and needs for health care are almost unlimited.  And a sordid reality is that there is already a tendency to resort to euthanasia when the money runs short.   A health care solution that encourages people to die early so as to ‘not be such a burden on society’ is not a health care solution, it is a nazi regime.  Whatever we do, we need to guard against this vigilantly.

Making all this even more complicated, is that medical science is far from exact. Not only do we wonder whether it is worth the expense to give mom that chemotherapy, we aren’t even sure whether chemotherapy is really what she needs.   And she might or might not want it as part of her treatment, no matter how beneficial the rest of us find it.

–>  As a result of this, nationalized health care systems are very popular with people whose alternative is no treatment at all.  But those who can afford to pay for the treatment of their choice (or would be able if only they weren’t being taxed to pay for everyone else’s treatment) often beg to differ with the medical bureaucrats’ decision over what treatment is the best one.  A just health care system would take into account both sets of concerns.

Likewise, there is much argument about what deserves to be covered as a ‘health care cost’ and what does not.  For example, under a typical insurance program in the US today, it is pretty easy to get coverage for a surgery that will restore your ability to use an injured leg.  But coverage for adaptive equipment that compensates for the loss of use of that same limb can be ridiculously difficult to obtain.  Even if the equipment in question costs less than the surgery.  Not proposing here that we use equipment instead of surgery.  Am proposing that part of the equation is a review of what we mean by health care, and what our goals are.   A just health care system extends benefits fairly, not treating some conditions as more privileged than others.

Finally, we should keep in mind that like all problems, health care issues need to be attacked from a thousand angles.  This or that program by itself won’t fix everything.  You have to constantly be looking at malpractice issues, at the system for educating a licensing medical professionals, at the management of costs, at the way our health care businesses are organized, all of it.  Insurance programs are only one part of the picture.

***

Enough for today.  I’ll keep going in the next installment.  Have a good weekend.